The key to understanding fiduciary principles, and why, when and
how they are applied, rests in first discerning the various public policy
objectives the fiduciary standard of conduct is designed to meet. This blog posts sets forth several of these public policy objectives, in hope of further contributing to the discussion on current regulatory initiatives.
Fiduciary
Status Addresses “Overreaching” When Person-To-Person Advice is Provided
The Investment Advisers Act of 1940 ("Advisers Act") embodied state common law's existing application of the fiduciary standard of conduct to those providing personalized investment advice. State common law continues to apply this standard to those who provide personalized investment advice and whom are in relatinoships of trust and confidence with their clients. In other words, the Advisers Act never stated that brokers were not fiduciaries - it just ensured that a certain type of advisor - those receiving special compensation - would always be considered fiduciaries.
The U.S. Supreme Court stated that the Advisers Act “recognizes that, with respect
to a certain class of investment advisers, a type of personalized relationship
may exist with their clients … The essential purpose of [the Advisers Act] is
to protect the public from the frauds and misrepresentations of unscrupulous
tipsters and touts and to safeguard the honest investment adviser against the
stigma of the activities of these individuals by making fraudulent practices by
investment advisers unlawful.”[1] “The Act was designed to apply to those
persons engaged in the investment-advisory profession -- those who provide
personalized advice attuned to a client's concerns, whether by written or
verbal communication[2] … The
dangers of fraud, deception, or overreaching that motivated the enactment of
the statute are present in personalized communications ….”[3]
Consumers’
Lack of Desire to Expend Time and Resources on Monitoring
The inability of clients to protect themselves while receiving
guidance from a fiduciary does not arise solely due to a significant knowledge
gap or due to the inability to expend funds for monitoring of the
fiduciary.
Even highly knowledgeable and
sophisticated clients (including many financial institutions) rely upon
fiduciaries. While they may possess the
financial resources to engage in stringent monitoring, and may even possess the
requisite knowledge and skill to undertake monitoring themselves, the
expenditure of time and money to undertake monitoring would deprive the
investors of time to engage in other activities. Indeed, since sophisticated and wealthy
investors have the ability to protect themselves, one might argue they might as
well manage their investments themselves and save the fees. Yet, reliance upon
fiduciaries is undertaken by wealthy and highly knowledgeable investors and
without expenditures of time and money for monitoring of the fiduciary. In this manner, “fiduciary duties are linked
to a social structure that values specialization of talents and functions.”
Tamar Frankel, Ch. 12, United States Mutual Fund Investors, Their Managers and
Distributors, in Conflicts Of Interest:
Corporate Governance And Financial Markets (Kluwer Law International,
The Netherlands, 2007), edited by Luc Thévenoz and Rashid Barhar.
The Shifting of
Monitoring Costs to Government
In service provider relationships which arise to the level
of fiduciary relations, it is highly costly for the client to monitor, verify
and ensure that the fiduciary will abide by the fiduciary’s promise and deal
with the entrusted power only for the benefit of the client. Indeed, if a client could easily protect
himself or herself from an abuse of the fiduciary advisor’s power, authority,
or delegation of trust, then there would be no need for imposition of fiduciary
duties. Hence, fiduciary status is
imposed as a means of aiding consumers in navigating the complex financial
world, by enabling trust to be placed in the advisor by the client.
Fiduciary relationships are relationships in which the fiduciary
provides to the client a service that public policy encourages. When such services are provided, the law
recognizes that the client does not possess the ability, except at great cost,
to monitor the exercise of the fiduciary’s powers. Usually the client cannot afford the expense
of engaging separate counsel or experts to monitor the conflicts of interest
the person in the superior position will possess, as such costs might outweigh
the benefits the client receives from the relationship with the fiduciary. Enforcement of the protections thereby
afforded to the client by the presence of fiduciary duties is shifted to the
courts and/or to regulatory bodies. Accordingly, a significant portion of the
cost of enforcement of fiduciary duties is shifted from individual clients to
the taxpayers, although licensing and related fees, as well as fines, may shift
monitoring costs back to all of the fiduciaries which are regulated.
Consumers’
Difficulty in Tying Performance To Results
The results of the services provided by a fiduciary advisor are
not always related to the honesty of the fiduciary or the quality of the
services. For example, an investment
adviser may be both honest and diligent, but the value of the client’s
portfolio may fall as the result of market events. Indeed, rare is the instance in which an
investment adviser provides substantial positive returns for each incremental period
over long periods of time – and in such instances the honesty of the investment
adviser should be suspect (as was the situation with Madoff).
Consumers’
Difficulty in Identifying and Understanding Conflicts Of Interest
Most individual consumers of financial services in America today
are unable to identify and understand the many conflicts of interest which can
exist in financial services. For
example, a customer of a broker-dealer firm might be aware of the existence of
a commission for the sale of a mutual fund, but possess no understanding that
there are many mutual funds available which are available without commissions
(i.e., sales loads). Moreover, brokerage
firms have evolved into successful disguisers of conflicts of interest arising
from third-party payments, including payments through such mechanisms as
contingent deferred sales charges, 12b-1 fees, payment for order flow, payment
for shelf space, and soft dollar compensation.
Survey after survey (including the Rand Report) has concluded that
consumers place a very high degree of trust and confidence in their investment
adviser, stockbroker, or financial planner.
These consumers deal with their advisors on unequal terms, and often are
unable to identify the conflicts of interest their “financial consultants”
possess. As evidence of the lack of
knowledge possessed by consumers, the Rand Report noted that 30% of investors
believed that they did not pay their financial consultant any fees! This calls into substantial question the
conclusion derived from the Rand Report’s survey that most customers of brokers
are happy with their financial consultant.
Transparency is important, but even when compensation is fully
disclosed, few individual investors realize the impact high fees and costs can
possess on their long-term investment returns; often individual investors
believe that a more expensive product will possess higher returns.[4]
For
Fiduciaries the Cost of Proving Trustworthiness Is Quite High
How does one prove one to be “honest” and “loyal”? The cost to a fiduciary in proving that the
advisor is trustworthy could be extremely high – so high as to exceed the
compensation gained from the relationships with the advisors’ clients.
- As a result of the Commission’s report to Congress, the Senate Committee on Banking and Currency determined that a solution to the problems of investment advisory services could not be affected without federal legislation. In addition, both the Senate and House Committees considering the legislation determined that it was needed not only to protect the public, but also to protect bona fide investment counselors from the stigma attached to the activities of unscrupulous tipsters and touts. During the debate in Congress, the special professional relationship between advisers and their clients was recognized. It is, said one representative, “somewhat [like that] of a physician to his patient.” The same Congressman continued that members of the profession were “to be complimented for their desire to improve the status of their profession and to improve its quality.”[5]
This is why it is important to fiduciary advisors to be able to
distinguish themselves from non-fiduciaries.
A recent example of the problems faced by investment advisers was the
“fee-based brokerage accounts” final rule adopted by the SEC in 2005, which would
have permitted brokers to provide the same functional investment advisory
services as investment advisers but without application of fiduciary standards
of conduct. This would have negated to a
large degree economic incentives[6] for
persons to become investment advisers and be subject to the higher standard of
conduct. The SEC’s fee-based accounts
rule was overturned in Financial Planning
Ass'n v. S.E.C., 482 F.3d 481 (D.C. Cir., 2007).
Monitoring
and Reputational Threats are Largely Ineffective
The ability of “the market” to monitor and enforce a fiduciary’s
obligations, such as through the compulsion to preserve a firm’s reputation, is
often ineffective in fiduciary relationships. This is because revelations about
abuses of trust by fiduciaries can be well hidden (such as through mandatory
arbitration clauses and secrecy agreements regarding settlements), or because
marketing efforts by fiduciary firms are so strong and pervasive that they
overwhelm the reported instances of breaches of fiduciary duties.
Public
Policy Encourages Specialization, Which Necessitates Fiduciary Duties
As Professor Tamar Frankel, long the leading scholar in the area
of fiduciary law as applied to securities regulation, once noted: “[A]
prosperous economy develops specialization. Specialization requires
interdependence. And interdependence cannot exist without a measure of
trusting. In an entirely non-trusting relationship interaction would be too
expensive and too risky to maintain. Studies have shown a correlation between the
level of trusting relationships on which members of a society operate and the
level of that society’s trade and economic prosperity.”[7] Fiduciary duties are imposed by law when
public policy encourages specialization in particular services, such as investment
management or law, in recognition of the value such services provide to our
society. For example, the provision of
investment consulting services under fiduciary duties of loyalty and due care
encourages participation by investors in our capital markets system. Hence, in order to promote public policy
goals, the law requires the imposition of fiduciary status upon the party in
the dominant position. Through the
imposition of such fiduciary status the client is thereby afforded various
protections. These protections serve to
reduce the risks to the client which relate to the service, and encourage the
client to utilize the service. Fiduciary
status thereby furthers the public interest.
Public Policy
Encourages Participation in our Capital Markets
Investment advisory services encourage participation by investors
in our capital markets system, which in turn promotes economic growth. The first and overriding responsibility any
financial professional has is to all of the participants of the market. This
primary obligation is required in order to maintain the perception[8] and
reality that the market is a fair game and thus encourage the widest possible
participation in the capital allocation process. The premise of the U.S.
capital market is that the widest possible participation in the market will
result in the most efficient allocation of financial resources and, therefore,
will lead to the best operation of the U.S. and world-wide economy. Indeed, academic research has revealed that
individual investors who are unable to trust their financial advisors are less
likely to participate in the capital markets.[9]
As stated in a 2002 white paper
authored by Professor Macy: “If people do not make
careful, rational decisions about how to self-regulate the patterns of
consumption and savings and investment over their life cycles, government will
have to step in to save people from the consequences of their poor planning.
Indeed the entire concept of government-sponsored, forced withholding for
retirement (Social Security) is based on the assumption that people lack the
foresight or the discipline, or the expertise to plan for themselves. The
weaknesses in government-sponsored social security and retirement systems
places increased importance on the ability of people to secure for themselves
adequate financial planning.”[10]
More blog posts to come, which will examine the fiduciary duties of those who provide personalized investment advice and comment on current regulatory and professional developments. To be apprised of blog postings, please subscribe to this blog, or follow me on Twitter (@140ltd) or connect with me on LinkedIn. Thank you. - Ron Rhoades, JD, CFP(r)
[1] Lowe v. SEC, 472 U.S. 181, 200, 201 (1985).
[2] Id. at 208.
[3] Id. at 210.
[4] In a recent study, Professors “Madrian, Choi
and Laibson recruited two groups of students in the summer of 2005 -- MBA
students about to begin their first semester at Wharton, and undergraduates
(freshmen through seniors) at Harvard.
All participants were asked to make hypothetical investments of $10,000,
choosing from among four S&P 500 index funds. They could put all their
money into one fund or divide it among two or more. ‘We chose the index funds
because they are all tracking the same index, and there is no variation in the
objective of the funds,’ Madrian says … ‘Participants received the prospectuses
that fund companies provide real investors … the students ‘overwhelmingly fail
to minimize index fund fees,’ the researchers write. ‘When we make fund fees
salient and transparent, subjects' portfolios shift towards lower-fee index
funds, but over 80% still do not invest everything in the lowest-fee fund’ …
[Said Professor Madrian,] ‘What our study suggests is that people do not know
how to use information well.... My guess is it has to do with the general level
of financial literacy, but also because the prospectus is so long." Knowledge@Wharton, “Today's Research
Question: Why Do Investors Choose High-fee Mutual Funds Despite the Lower
Returns?” citing Choi, James J., Laibson, David I. and Madrian, Brigitte C.,
“Why Does the Law of One Price Fail? An Experiment on Index Mutual Funds”
(March 6, 2008). Yale ICF Working Paper No. 08-14. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1125023.
[5] John H. Walsh, “A Simple Code Of Ethics: A
History of the Moral Purpose Inspiring Federal Regulation of the Securities
Industry,” 29 Hofstra L.Rev. 1015, 1066-8 (2001), citing
SEC, REPORT ON INVESTMENT COUNSEL, INVESTMENT MANAGEMENT, INVESTMENT
SUPERVISORY, AND INVESTMENT ADVISORY SERVICES (1939).
[6] One might reasonably ask
why “honest investment advisers” (to use the language of the U.S. Supreme Court
in SEC vs. Capital Gains) had to be
protected by the Advisers Act. Was it
not enough to just protect consumers?
The answer can be found in economic principles, as set forth in the
classic thesis for which George Akerlof won a Nobel Prize:
There are many markets in which buyers use some market
statistic to judge the quality of prospective purchases. In this case there is
incentive for sellers to market poor quality merchandise, since the returns for
good quality accrue mainly to the entire group whose statistic is affected
rather than to the individual seller. As a result there tends to be a reduction
in the average quality of goods and also in the size of the market.
George A. Akerloff, The Market for "Lemons":
Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism, The Quarterly Journal of
Economics, Vol. 84, No. 3. (Aug., 1970), p.488.
George Akerloff demonstrated “how in situations of asymmetric
information (where the seller has information about product quality unavailable
to the buyer), ‘dishonest dealings tend to drive honest dealings out of the
market.’ Beyond the unfairness of the dishonesty that can occur, this process
results in less overall dealing and less efficient market transactions.” Frank B. Cross and Robert A. Prentice, The
Economic Value of Securities Regulation, 28 Cardoza L.Rev. 334, 366
(2006). As George Akerloff explained:
“[T]he presence of people who wish to pawn bad wares as good wares tends to
drive out the legitimate business. The cost of dishonesty, therefore, lies not
only in the amount by which the purchaser is cheated; the cost also must
include the loss incurred from driving legitimate business out of
existence.” Akerloff at p. 495.
[7] Tamar Frankel, Trusting And Non-Trusting:
Comparing Benefits, Cost And Risk, Working Paper 99-12, Boston University
School of Law.
[8] “Applying the Advisers Act and its fiduciary
protections is essential to preserve the participation of individual investors
in our capital markets. NAPFA members
have personally observed individual investors who have withdrawn from investing
in stocks and mutual funds due to bad experiences with registered
representatives and insurance agents in which the customer inadvertently placed
his or her trust into the arms-length relationship.” Letter of National Association of Investment
advisers (NAPFA) dated March 12, 2008 to David Blass, Assistant Director,
Division of Investment Management, SEC re: Rand Study.
[9] “We find that trusting
individuals are significantly more likely to buy stocks and risky assets and,
conditional on investing in stock, they invest a larger share of their wealth
in it. This effect is economically very important: trusting others increases
the probability of buying stock by 50% of the average sample probability and
raises the share invested in stock by 3.4 percentage points … lack of trust can
explain why individuals do not participate in the stock market even in the
absence of any other friction … [W]e also show that, in practice, differences
in trust across individuals and countries help explain why some invest in
stocks, while others do not. Our simulations also suggest that this problem can
be sufficiently severe to explain the percentage of wealthy people who do not
invest in the stock market in the United States and the wide variation in this
percentage across countries.” Guiso, Luigi, Sapienza, Paola and Zingales,
Luigi. “Trusting the Stock Market” (May 2007); ECGI - Finance Working Paper No.
170/2007; CFS Working Paper No. 2005/27; CRSP Working Paper No. 602. Available
at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=811545.
[10] Macy, Jonathan R.,
“Regulation of Financial Planners” (April 2002), a White Paper prepared for the
Financial Planning Association; http://fpanet.org/docs/assets/ExecutiveSummaryregulationoffps.pdf provides an Executive
Summary of the paper.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Please respect our readers by not posting commercial advertisements nor critical reviews of any particular firm or individual. Thank you.